The Changing Economics of Energy Conservation

With oil prices spiking above $60 a barrel, Persian Gulf production threatened by political instability, and exploding demand from China and India likely to strain supplies for decades to come, surely it is time for Washington to get serious about energy conservation.

Well, yes . . . and no. While most economists (including me) are deeply skeptical about the value of government mandates for energy efficiency, in principle there is a case to be made for using taxes to "internalize" the costs of consumption that are not otherwise reflected in prices. But those costs are lower than you might expect--lower, perhaps, than the taxes currently charged at the pump. Moreover, while oil-security worries are now driving the calls for conservation, a careful look suggests that the neglected costs are actually related to traffic congestion and the threat of global warming. Taxing oil consumption (as opposed to taxing urban road use or carbon emissions from all fuels) would hardly get to the roots of these problems.

Disturbing Dependence

First, the security issue. Yes, the world has grown disturbingly dependent on oil from politically unstable countries, increasing the risk of devastating supply disruptions. But most of those costs are already reflected in the cost of doing business. Oil-dependent companies (including gasoline retailers) can and do take account of the risks by stockpiling fuel. Indeed, one criticism of ongoing government investment in emergency oil reserves--the Strategic Petroleum Reserve now contains 700 million barrels--is that it undermines private incentives to insure against supply disruptions.

OK, but the U.S. Government does spend a bundle in military and diplomatic resources in the Mideast, and one of the objectives of Mideast policy is to keep the oil flowing. Shouldn't those outlays be reflected in consumers' energy bills?

The answer isn't obvious. Expenditures to maintain America's perceived interests in oil-rich parts of the world don't necessarily increase oil supplies. For example, the most reliable way to get more oil out of Iraq would almost certainly have been to leave Saddam in powerand lift the sanctions on his regime. More generally, the most reliable suppliers of oil are countries that are desperate for the money to keep their economies afloat and their citizens tranquil--think Saudi Arabia, Nigeria, Iran and Venezuela. U.S. policies aimed at deterring terrorism or keeping the sea lanes open aren't likely to affect their behavior.

The Tax Fix

After the oil shocks of the 1970s, some economists made a very different case for reducing dependence on foreign oil. Cutting U.S. demand with higher taxes, they argued, would break the ability of the OPEC cartel (and, in particular, Saudi Arabia) to keep prices high. In other words, instead of paying Saudi princes, we could pay ourselves.

That price leverage may or may not have existed three decades ago--even then the cartel might have had the political will to counter the gambit by further restricting supply. But it is hard to argue that,in a global economy consuming some 85 million barrels of crude a day, even a doubling of the federal excise tax on gasoline (that would cut consumption by an estimated half-million barrels a day) would significantly reduce world oil prices.

So how about using taxes to internalize the very real (if more mundane) costs associated with traffic congestion? Higher taxes at the pump would, one presumes, encourage more carpooling and greater use ofmass transit. But the tax would not discriminate between driving on congested and uncongested roads. Moreover, much of its impact on roaduse would be dissipated in a matter of a few years, as drivers shifted to more fuel-efficient (but no less congestion-making) vehicles. The moral: if you want to use taxes to cut road congestion, tax road use in congested areas directly--as they already do very successfully in London and Singapore.

Global Warming

That leaves one economically respectable argument for using taxes to internalize energy costs: global warming. Burning any fossil fuel generates carbon dioxide emissions, which are likely to raise the average temperature of the earth's surface. And in the long run, warmingis likely to affect climate in ways that many of us won't like, raising sea levels, changing rainfall patterns and making storms more damaging. Probably the best researched (though, still quite speculative)estimate of this external cost comes from William Nordhaus of Yale, who put the figure at less than $15 per ton of carbon in today's dollars.

Note, however, that all fossil fuels aren't equal in emitting carbon as they yield energy. And liquid fuels score pretty well by this measure: $15 per ton of carbon is equal to just 4 cents a gallon of gasoline. Indeed, the only fossil fuel on which a tax of this magnitudewould have much impact on use is coal.

We don't know whether energy prices will remain near historic peaks, or whether a combination of market-induced conservation and increases in fuel production will bring them back to 1990s levels. What we're pretty sure about, though, is that most of the cost of oil and gasconsumption is already borne by consumers. Accordingly, the case forgovernment-induced (as opposed to market-induced) conservation that doesn't focus on coal is, at best, problematic.

Robert Hahn is a resident scholar at AEI and director of the AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies. Peter Passell is a senior fellow at the Milken Institute.

Also Visit
AEIdeas Blog The American Magazine

What's new on AEI

image Dad and the diploma: The difference fathers make for college graduation
image A better way to finance that college degree
image Fracking for bigger budgets
image Earth Day: Hail fossil fuels, energy of the future
AEI on Facebook
Events Calendar
  • 21
    MON
  • 22
    TUE
  • 23
    WED
  • 24
    THU
  • 25
    FRI
Wednesday, April 23, 2014 | 12:00 p.m. – 1:30 p.m.
Graduation day: How dads’ involvement impacts higher education success

Join a diverse group of panelists — including sociologists, education experts, and students — for a discussion of how public policy and culture can help families lay a firmer foundation for their children’s educational success, and of how the effects of paternal involvement vary by socioeconomic background.

Thursday, April 24, 2014 | 12:00 p.m. – 1:30 p.m.
Getting it right: A better strategy to defeat al Qaeda

This event will coincide with the release of a new report by AEI’s Mary Habeck, which analyzes why current national security policy is failing to stop the advancement of al Qaeda and its affiliates and what the US can do to develop a successful strategy to defeat this enemy.

Friday, April 25, 2014 | 9:15 a.m. – 1:15 p.m.
Obamacare’s rocky start and uncertain future

During this event, experts with many different views on the ACA will offer their predictions for the future.   

No events scheduled this day.
No events scheduled this day.
No events scheduled this day.
No events scheduled this day.
No events scheduled this day.